|
Monetary policy facing new challengesThe Covid-19 crisis has triggered the strongest global recession ever seen. Its duration and depth are still very uncertain. In order to avoid a major financial crisis, governments and CBs have been quick to put in place large-scale programmes. The economic policies implemented on both sides of the Atlantic are unprecedented, with stabilisation plans equivalent to 10-20% of GDP (including loans and guarantees) and CBs committing, more or less explicitly, to acquiring equivalent amounts of securities. CBs are by nature more flexible than governments insofar as parliaments are not involved in their decision-making process. They were thus the most proactive in this crisis, lowering – when it was still possible – their key interest rates and reintroducing large-scale asset-purchase programmes financed by money creation (i.e., QE policies). Arguing that circumstances were exceptional, they have not only committed themselves to increase their balance sheet at a pace not seen before, but have also crossed new limits. This can be exemplified, for instance, on the Fed’s side, with the acquisition of ‘fallen angels’ bonds, and, on the ECB’s side, with the decision to deviate temporarily, but significantly, from any rule of proportionality1. By committing to buy government and corporate debt, CBs contribute to maintaining very low nominal bond yields and containing debt service. In other words, they ease the solvency constraint. This is particularly true for public debt. Sovereign-debt issuance (net of CB redemptions and purchases) will be negative in the major advanced economies in 2020. In the United States, this is the first time this has happened. At the end of the day, governments have become the buyers of last resort, while CBs are playing their role as lenders of last resort. Basically, the principle on which their joint action is based is that there is always a possibility, even in a liquidity trap, of stimulating global demand through a proper combination of monetary and fiscal policy. Historically, economic and financial crises have always given the authorities the opportunity to equip themselves with the appropriate instruments or regulations to contain them2. However, with this pandemic, a spectacular change in economic policy has taken place in just a few months: fiscal and monetary policies have become intertwined, and this is probably not reversible. How far can CBs go? This issue is quite controversial. The long-term economic consequences of non-conventional policies (large-scale asset purchases and/or negative rates) are still primarily unknown, since CBs had never before increased the size of their balance sheets to such an extent, nor lowered their interest rates in negative territory. We argue here that CBs are still far from being out of ammunition, and may continue to explore new avenues looking ahead, like helicopter money, debt cancellation, yield-curve control or even (very) negative interest rates. First, we will carry out a brief review of QE policies, stressing their diversity. Then, we will look at the possibility for CBs to explore new avenues, either through yield-curve control or very negative nominal interest rates. We will then look at the possible macrofinancial impact and the consequences for investors. Public-debt monetisation, ‘fiscal QE’ and helicopter moneyIt is important to understand the impact of CB policies on their balance sheets in order to understand the paths forward. Let’s recall briefly the basics of QEs. Under QE policies, the size of the CB’s balance sheet increases simultaneously on both the liability and the asset side. In its narrowest sense, QE consists of issuing money to acquire government securities3. Technically, on the liability side, the commercial banks’ reserves with the CB (the amount of money in circulation) increase; while the CB’s claim on the government that it has acquired is shown on the asset side4. Another form of QE consists of purchasing private-sector securities (corporate bonds or even equities). This type of QE is sometimes presented as a ‘fiscal QE’ because it can be broken down theoretically into two distinct operations: a QE on government debt and a parallel issuance of government-debt securities to buy private assets. This type of QE is qualified as ‘fiscal’, as it implicitly uses taxpayer guarantees to subsidise private firms. Helicopter money5 (direct transfers from the CB to private agents) is another form of QE that has very different consequences for the CB’s balance sheet. Under helicopter money, the money created is supposed to support directly aggregate demand6. In theory, helicopter money is equivalent to a fiscal stimulus financed by the CB7. However if CBs directly transfer money to private agents, the transfer becomes permanent8. The increase in the balance sheet no longer corresponds to an increase in the Treasury’s debt to the CB, and public finance metrics (deficit- and debt-to-GDP ratios) remain unchanged despite additional expenditure. This option is thus technically different from debt monetisation, at least when the balance sheets of the Treasury and the CB are duly separated. As a result, the CB falls in negative equity. In theory, the Treasury would have to opt for recapitalisation. For that, the government may issue a perpetual zero-coupon bond. However, this CB’s claim on the government would be fictitious insofar as it has no time horizon. However, CBs do not face the same constraints as commercial banks. In particular, there is nothing to prevent a CB from continuing to operate, even when it is in a negative-equity position. Yet this option has its limitations. If money creation far exceeds a CB’s assets, this can generate a widespread loss of confidence and inflation expectations that would lead to increased savings or flight to real assets (e.g., gold, real estate). Finally, note that, from a fundamental point of view, nothing prevents the CB from writing off the sovereign debt it has accumulated or from keeping it indefinitely on its balance sheet by rolling bonds over as they mature. Debt cancellation would be akin to helicopter money. If the CB decides to restructure some or all of the debt accumulated under past asset-purchase programmes, this is a form of transfer to the Treasury9. Given all the legal issues that CBs would face by doing so, they are exploring other avenues. Yield-curve control (YCC) back to the forefrontWith CB key rates close to zero, yieldcurve control policies (YCC) are back in thespotlight. During YCC, the CB seeks to control a particular point or segment of the yield curve (often the ten-year yield). To do so, the CB implicitly commits itself to purchase the amounts of government bonds needed to achieve its objective. If the CB is credible, owing to market arbitrage, bond yields tend to move close to their target. The YCC is often akin to a form of QE but with different modalities: bond purchases adjust to bond yields, and not the other way around. The CB thus loses the control of its balance sheet. The yield peg could even lead the CB to reduce its balance sheet (quantitative tapering): this could be the case if private-investor demand exceeds the government financing needs (new issuance and refinancing). The YCC was implemented in the United States in the post-war period, until 1947. Since 2016, the BoJ has explicitly targeted the ten-year JGB yield rate at zero: this policy, combined with negative key rates, has been successful insofar as it has allowed the BoJ to reduce its bond purchases and contain its balance sheet. The most recent FOMC minutes show that the YCC is being seriously considered by the Fed. The YCC is possible in real monetary unions (e.g., United States, Japan, United Kingdom) where there is only one single public-debt instrument. However, it is not in the Eurozone for at least two reasons. First, because the ECB would have to target several yield curves simultaneously, one for each member state. In addition to operational difficulty, there would be a political obstacle: the ECB has no legitimacy to estimate the credit risk embedded in each sovereign debt. Whatever the target, it would be subject to endless political debate. Secondly, the ECB would face a legal problem because it would have to commit (ex-ante) to buying assets without any rule of proportionality, or even to monetising public debt, which is prohibited by the TFEU. Think the unthinkable: (very) negative nominal interest ratesSince the 1980s, CBs have always cut their key interest rates very sharply during recessions. Major CBs (Fed, ECB, BoJ) have on average lowered their rates by around 4% in response to severe recessions. However, in the current environment of low inflation in advanced economies, CBs have less room for manoeuvre when key rates reach their ‘zero lower bound’ (ZLB). But the ZLB is not a law of nature. Between 2012 and 2016, certain CBs have tried to free themselves from this bound. The CBs of Switzerland, Sweden, Denmark, Japan and the ECB reduced their key rates below zero for the first time in economic history, but ultimately only marginally. The effectiveness of negative interest rate policies (NIRPs) is still highly controversial. Large financial institutions remain very strongly opposed to it10. The dominant view among economists is that nominal interest rates cannot be expected to move significantly below zero. In this case, economic agents would prefer to hoard their money in the form of cash, so that CBs could no longer stimulate demand and credit. Another argument most often put forward is that negative rates reduce banks’ profitability and lead them to reduce their lending. Do not forget that it is ultimately the real interest rate, not the nominal rate, that matters for the economy. CBs are often wrongly blamed for the excessively low level of interest rates. But they are in fact just as much victims of falling real interest rates as commercial banks. Moreover, real interest rates are not determined by monetary policy in the long run. Global real interest rates have fallen since the mid-1980s for structural reasons11. Certain economists12 thus continue to promote NIRPs and even say that nominal interest rates can be put in very negative territory. In practice, they argue that legal, regulatory and tax measures could increase the cost of cash hoarding13. Contrary to the conventional wisdom, it would not be necessary to eliminate paper currency14. Let us mention that if the Fed is still strongly opposed to the NIRP15, the BoE now seems to consider seriously this possibility. However, let us be clear: for practical reasons, the introduction of very negative key rates cannot happen overnight. Such a move would have to be prepared well in advance. We cannot deny that technology and electronic money are opening up new avenues through the traditional interest-rate channel. But we believe that this option would only be envisaged if the other options fail (i.e., if deflationary pressures intensify). CBs have moved in uncharted territory and macrofinancial stability is at stakeWith QE policies, there is no longer a clear boundary between fiscal and monetary policy16. Subsequently, should there be a conflict between CB’s mandate and government’s objectives (cyclical stabilisation, public-debt sustainability), CB operational independence could be in jeopardy17. We believe this risk is more pronounced in the United States – where the Fed operates under close congressional oversight – than in the Eurozone, where the ECB’s independence is enshrined in an international Treaty. If the Fed were to lose its operational independence, it could de-anchor inflation expectations, and the consequences could be disastrous for the US dollar. Even if CBs keep their independence, giving the illusion that money can always be created ex nihilois like opening Pandora’s box, with demands of all kinds (pension increases, tax cuts, wage increases, etc.) which are potential sources of inflation. In the current regime, characterised by low nominal GDP growth, short-term interest rates close to zero and very high debts by historical standards, the benefits of monetisation seem to outweigh the costs. Let us recall that some historical experiences with debt monetisation have been successful (Japan in the 1930s or Canada after the Second World War)18. Nevertheless, the unlimited expansion of CB balance sheets could lead to a collapse in the external value of the currency. States that have little credibility on the international stage – many emerging countries are in this case – cannot implement this type of policy. On a global scale, unlimited QEs might even trigger a crisis in the international monetary system, with the potential for a general flight to real assets (property bubble, gold, etc.), or even encourage the development of crypto-currencies. As an alternative to traditional QEs, YYC could reinforce the forward guidance with a strong commitment to maintain long-term bond yields at low levels. As a complement (or an alternative), negative key rates could ultimately boost inflation expectations and steepen the yield curve. Such a move would benefit to banks and could help corporates and households to renegotiate their debts. Both QEs and negative nominal interest rates have unwelcome side effects19. By anchoring the risk-free rate at a very low level for a long period, these policies distort market prices and tend to inflate risky assets, regardless to their fundamentals. QEs are clearly welcome when risky assets are undervalued (this was the case just after the great financial crisis in 2008). However, they may ultimately generate bubbles on a wide range of assets (corporate credit, equities, real estate, illiquid assets etc.), endangering macro-financial stability. Not to mention that by favouring capital holders (i.e. the wealthiest), they also have unwelcome distributional effects. What are the consequences for investors?Financial repression and fiscal dominance are here to stay. Ultimately, most of the monetary policy options imply that nominal rates will have to remain low for a considerable period. This is in practice the only way to ensure public-debt sustainability. In theory, the monetary policies envisaged, when combined with fiscal stimulus, should eventually revive economies and raise inflation expectations, probably above the official targets of the major CBs (2%). Given the level of leverage in the system (both private and public debt at historical highs), some inflation would be welcome by the authorities. Against this backdrop, the Fed and the ECB strategic reviews, which have been delayed by the crisis, may soon come back to the forefront and will be scrutinised by investors20.
In addition, we see other various consequences for investors: The above consequences for investors are not immediate, and are still largely hypothetical, in particular when it comes to consequences for the fair value of risky assets when bond yields are controlled and artificially maintained at low levels. Ultimately, we cannot rule out new bubbles, the bursting of which could jeopardise macrofinancial stability. Regulation and taxation may thus have to be mobilised to contain asset-price inflation, particularly with regard to property market. Unconventional monetary policies call for more regulation, not less. ConclusionsContrary to the conventional wisdom, monetary policy options are far from having been all fully explored. Given CB proactivity, we do believe that reflation is at hand with a well-calibrated dosage between monetary and fiscal policy. On the one hand, this will require more risk monitoring from regulators, while on the other, this should open new opportunities to investors. In all likelihood, CBs will continue to manage actively their balance sheet in order to ease the financial constraints that would otherwise weigh on the private and public sectors that are heavily indebted. Public and private debts owed to CBs can be easily rolled over time. This can alleviate the debt burden on the most leveraged agents. However, CBs alone cannot be expected to do the impossible: they cannot make companies whose prospects have deteriorated creditworthy. Thus, bankruptcies and defaults may still be on the cards in certain sectors. Looking ahead, the scale of the Covid-19 crisis is such that it will likely encourage CBs to explore new avenues, of which all may have unwelcome side effects. Should this crisis deepen, we should be prepared to ‘think the unthinkable’: full-blown debt monetisation, helicopter money or very negative nominal interest rates. |
|
__________________________________
1. The ECB’s purchases are supposed to follow the capital keys (proportion to the national CB share of the ECB’s capital). |