Summary Should the €2,800 billion in sovereign bonds or the equivalent* that are on the European Central Bank’s balance sheet be treated just like any other bonds? This question, which has come up regularly over the past several months, is far from being of mere academic interest. In fact, it is symptomatic of a wish to forgive or even cancel a portion of the public debt being raised to cope with the Covid-19 crisis. But, rather than simply ignoring it, a more standard solution for the financial markets would be to regard such debt as virtual for the moment and to exclude it temporarily from public debt ratios. |
November 2020 |
Novembre 2020
|
Certain asset characteristics are possibilities that are never realized. |
Emergency spending, followed by economic support plans launched in 2020, has sent public debt up sharply, to worrisome levels in many euro-area countries. However, most of the newly issued bonds are being bought up by the ECB; the market is absorbing only a little more than usual1. Government borrowers and the ECB have said repeatedly that such debt cannot be cancelled and will one day be paid back. Moreover, this is in the public interest, as cancelling or restructuring some or all of this debt would devalue all European debt. Rather than simply ignoring the question or putting forth unrealistic solutions, it is worth asking how financial markets should treat it. Do the characteristics of a financial asset change when it switches owners? From the strictly legal point of view, the obvious answer is no. Moreover, this is a fundamental principle that ensures equal treatment of bondholders, shareholders, creditors, etc. But if the rights or obligations embedded in a financial instrument are never exercised, can they be considered as more virtual than real? The financial markets often incorporate this parameter when the use that is made of an asset restricts de facto some of its characteristics. Markets constantly adjust to reality
Take, for example, the number of a company’s shares that are in free float calculation, which are often the only ones included in its weighting in market indices. The company’s own shares held in treasury are often excluded, along with those held by pact bound shareholders or by governments2. These shares exist, but they are regarded as not being freely traded on the market and are therefore left out of certain indices. This is the case, for example, of EDF, which is not in the CAC 40 index, even though its market cap exceeds €40 billion, as the French state holds 84% of its shares. |
The central bank has
Excluding sovereign |
Central Banks & Treasury special relationshipsIn the special case of European or US sovereign debt, an additional parameter must be included – the bond issuer and bondholder are of the same nature, i.e. public, not-for-profit institutions. The Federal Reserve’s response to the US Treasury’s issuance programme or the ECB’s launch of the PEPP while euro zone governments are expanding public deficits substantially, demonstrate close coordination and even conditionality between fiscal and monetary policy5. Not to mention the monetisation of public debt, an implicit pact is binding the government debtor with its central bank creditor. The central bank has pledged to permanently refrain from selling its bonds on the market and, moreover, to participate systematically in refinancing maturing debt, unless justified by financial conditions.
The question naturally arises from the above examples: does this debt held by the ECB or the Fed have the same characteristics as debt held on private investors’ balance sheets? The answer is probably no. For, if the bond issuer is certain that, over a horizon that surpasses the maturity of its issue, the bondholder will never sell it and will subscribe to a new issue upon maturity regardless of the price, it may rightly consider that this is not just any other bond. This is due to the central bank’s clearly announced intention but is also to the institutional nature of the two entities. For, if the state is assumed to be eternal it can forego paying off its debt and instead refinance it, or roll it over. The central bank, meanwhile, can keep buying it forever as part of its monetary policy mandate. Change of paradigmAs is the case for other assets, the markets should legitimately exclude sovereign debt that is on central bank balance sheets from the calculation of stat liabilities, as some of its characteristics have been altered for some time to come. Such an exclusion is as virtual as the debt is, and as temporary… but for a very long time. However, the currency issued by the central bank in exchange, is quite real. So, this matter should be approached less from the point of view of debt/GDP ratios or the equivalent, and more from the standpoint of the monetary base and monetary aggregates (M1, M2, M3 and L) and their counterparts (foreign debt, the state and the economy). Hence, non-conventional policies, when pushed to the extreme, can result in a new paradigm. They will force the financial markets to switch analytical frameworks and return indirectly to monetary theory notions that had been, somewhat cast aside. There is even talk of a return to the 1970s7.
* As of the end of September €2,290bn under PSPP and €510bn under PEPP. Source: ECB: link |